Nicholas T. Parsons
Scotland and the Union, Hungary and the Empire

Notes

In 1826 Sir Walter Scott set about his fictional Letters of Malachi Malagrowther Esq. to be published in the Edinburgh Weekly Journal and designed to knock on the head proposals recently put forward to “change everything in Scotland to an English model”. Scott was the most loyal of Scots—loyal to the Union, loyal to his Scottish heritage and over-loyal to his friends, a quality that ruined him financially. In his measured defence of his nation, there are parallels to be found with the mingled patriotism and realism that politically moderate Hungarians, such as Count István Széchenyi, exhibited in their conception of a more equal relationship between their country and the rigidly absolutist Habsburg state. Another entry in Scott’s Journal for February 26th, 1826, evokes the tone of this struggle for balance in the mind of a patriotic, moderate conservative: “Spent the morning and till dinner on Malachi’s second epistle to the Athenians. It is difficult to steer betwixt the natural impulse of one’s national feelings setting in one direction, and the prudent regard to the interests of the empire and its internal peace and quiet, recommending less vehement expression. I will endeavour to keep sight of both. But were my own interests alone concerned, damn me but I would give it them hot!”
If one broadens the canvas from personal feelings to that of a national identity, one can see that  the Anglo-Scottish contribution to European culture, and the position of Scotland culturally, politically and economically with regard to England, has some thought-provoking implications for the possible development of Hungary in the context of Habsburg hegemony. David Hume, Adam Ferguson, Adam Smith and other giants of the Scottish Enlightenment were the products of a Presbyterian-based, democratically organised educational system coupled with the economic benefits  that flowed from the Act of Union with England of 1707. As Jerry Muller has pointed out, their Calvinist heritage linked Scottish academe to the tradition of the great universities of the Netherlands, the Scottish development of Roman law brought its legal institutions closer to the continental legal framework than were those of England, while a historically determined tendency to draw inspiration from non-English sources, as well as links going back to “the auld alliance”, created a powerful axis with the thinkers of the French Enlightenment. Scottish intellectuals were often more genuinely cosmopolitan than their English counterparts (the Grand Tour of English milords being more an Olympian survey of foreigners coupled with a little opportunistic antiquity purchasing); theirs was a “provincial cosmopolitanism” implying a strong and pragmatic impulse for self-improvement.1  In other words, these “North Britons”, as the Lowland Scots intelligentsia preferred to style itself, capitalised on their distinctive cultural traditions to bring something distinctive to the notion of “Britain” and “British”, just as their descendants were to make a silk purse out of a sow’s ear by going out and running the British Empire, since they were denied the plum jobs in the English establishment. Perhaps it is no accident that the upwardly mobile Scot, Adam Clark, was the one who went abroad and grew in stature in his job as Baumeister supervising the construction of the Chain Bridge between Pest and Buda, while his superior, the Englishman Tierney Clark, was content to be (and could afford to be) a stay-at-home administrator of the project. Equally it may be significant that Adam Clark nobly supported the cause of his adopted Hungary in the 1848 War of Independence, while Tierney Clark was notoriously contemptuous of it.
 
 

The North Britons were anxious to be distinguished from the folk museum of the Highlands on their back doorstep—it was usually  Lowlanders and others who, as factors to the Highland landowners, were responsible for some of the most brutal of the so-called “clearances” when the feudal subsistence economy of the Highlands was being destroyed to make way for intensive sheep-runs, and whole clans were driven into exile in North America or the Antipodes. On the other hand, it was the Lowlander and antiquary, Sir Walter Scott, who rekindled the national myth of the Land of the Gaels that reinforced Scottish identity, succeeding in large measure in the invention of a Kulturvolk, despite the discredit potentially attaching to such an enterprise after the literary forgeries of  Ossian. Certainly much of Scott’s almost unparalleled international success as an author, not least in Hungary, may be attributed to his achievement in re-inventing a nation that had lost its independent statehood, and doing so by invoking a historical continuity that upheld national dignity. Robert Walsh in his Narrative of a Journey from Constantinople to England (1832) encounters a bookseller in Transylvanian Hermannstadt who has just placed a huge portrait on his wall of “Le sieur Valtere Skote, l’homme le plus célèbre en toute l’Europe”.2 French and German translations of Scott’s novels formed a sizeable part of his stock. John Paget encountered an impoverished Jew on his Hungarian travels, who pulled from his pocket a well-thumbed German translation of Ivanhoe, assuring the Englishman that he had read many others of Scott’s works and expressing profound dismay on learning that the great man was no longer alive.3
From the point of view of a progressive conservative, Scott’s genius lay in reconciling national aspirations with historical and political realities. His stage-management of George IV’s visit to Scotland in 1822 managed to flatter all interested parties: the Highlanders with the myth that the roots of Scottish identity lay in the (substantially invented) culture of the Gael, the “North Britons” with an emphasis on their contribution to the British weal and the Hanoverian monarch with a show of loyalty and affection which survived even the spectacle of  the corpulent German libertine sporting a kilt. The kind of ingenious marriage of myth and political convenience that Scott pulled off was closer to the “synthesis of enlightened Empiricism and romantic nationalism”  to be found in the thinking of Zsigmond Kemény and others of the “Literary Deák Party” than to Széchenyi’s  quasi-mystical Herderian idea of the individual nation’s unique mission, still less the myopic populism of Kossuth.4  Interestingly, Kemény, who stood for “mediatory liberalism”, was a popularizer of Lord Macaulay’s intensely Whig-orientated, Protestant and materialistic History of England in Hungary, drawing lessons from it for his homeland in a long review of Antal Csengery’s translation into Hungarian of the first part of the history published in 1853. Baron Eötvös was also of this group and it was he who coined the pregnant phrase “peaceful co-existence” (békés együttélés), a pragmatic locution that suggested a way of reconciling national aspiration with political and economic reality long before it acquired its particularised twentieth century meaning.
A curious insight into Kossuth’s (by comparison) more fundamentalist line of thought is given by remarks recorded of him at an interview with Gladstone in 1861, when the ex-Governor-President solicited support for his country against Austrian imperialism. He was told of “the difficulty that England would be under in favouring for the Austrian Empire a legislative disruption which she could not accept herself in somewhat parallel circumstances”. Kossuth rejoined that, Hungary being proportionately larger than Austria, the situation was as if the House of Commons sat in Edinburgh, not London. Gladstone, one of the rather few British politicians who was notably liberal in nationality questions, was unable to see the force of this remark, and most educated Scotsmen of the time would probably have found its reverse implication that Scotland was a colony of England both untrue and offensive. Kossuth was closer to the grain of history, if not to reality, when he later predicted that Ireland would eventually become one of the United States of America.5
 

It has been well said of Széchenyi that he envisaged “social reform as serving a national end”,6 a point underlined in his book Stadium where he stresses that all inhabitants of Hungary should enjoy legal equality or “civil status” (polgári lét). Scotland’s history held a certain allure for Hungarians precisely because it had been transmuted from independent kingdom to partner with England under one Stuart crown, then to a vital constituent of Britain after the 1707 Act of Union; and this without losing its distinctive culture or its institutional particularities, such as its currency (the proposed abolition of which stimulated Scott’s Malachi letters), the legal system, the educational framework and much of the arrangements for local government. By the time Adam Smith wrote The Wealth of Nations, the majority of  Scots were forward-looking, industrious and pragmatic, as befitted a country with economic growth rates equalling, in time even exceeding, those of England, and with a rising merchant and technocratic middle class, of which Adam Clark himself was to become a member through his skill and application. The situation would however have been even better, were not between a fifth and a third of  Scottish lands entailed, like the feudal lands of Hungary, and with the same consequences of lack of investment and an illiquid or non-existent land market. If Smith’s remarks seemed especially relevant to Hungary, it was because he could look out of his back window and observe that hitherto hereditary land owners had little incentive to improve the productivity of their land and their feudal dependents none at all. On the other hand, dynamic, ambitious Scots had decided to make the union with England work to their advantage, even whenever possible, to scale the heights of the English establishment. Had Habsburg Austria been as economically dynamic as England at that time, the moderate reformers who wanted partnership between Hungary and Austria, not an uncertain and probably doomed autarchy, might have had an easier task of political persuasion.
That Scottish growth rates were in large measure also the result of  the customs union with England distinguished the position of Scotland further from that of Hungary, which the Habsburgs were tempted to treat as a colony in the way Britain treated Ireland, periodically  making concessions when they were hard-pressed with a view to withdrawing them at a more opportune moment. No doubt Adam Smith’s espousal of free trade stemmed in part from the local  Scottish experience, but he also drew from it the vital distinction between “the mean principle of national prejudice” (mercantilism in effect being the pursuit of an undeclared war where another’s loss was the protagonist’s gain) and the “noble one of the love of one’s own country”.7 The success of the Scottish merchant class was doubtless attributable to Presbyterian virtues such as self-control, industriousness, and the deferral of gratification, but was also due to the enlightened pragmatism of  the cosmopolitan provincial, a pragmatism that regulated the Calvinist tendency to self-destruct on the altar of predestination. Adam Smith himself was a Whig in politics and a Deist in religion — again, he had only to look out of his back window to see the downside of Presbyterianism at work. Széchenyi’s remark that he wished to hear more of the the noble Hungarian and less about the Hungarian nobles is very much in the spirit of mainline Scottish thought which rejected the anachronistic feudalism still evident in parts of the country and favoured the trajectory of self-improvement that Walter Bagehot sardonically described as “showing how, from being a savage, man rose to become a Scotchman”.8
 
 

Such sentiments bring us back to Széchenyi’s view that the idea of the nation must be linked to the idea of national progress, which in turn should be viewed as an aspect of universal progress. In his surprisingly passionate defence of Walter Scott in his study of The Historical Novel, Georg Lukács remarks that “Scott gives a perfect artistic expression to the basic progressive tendency of this period, that is the historical defence of progress”. In support of this he quotes Balzac’s view that Scott passed from “the portrayal of past history to the portrayal of the present as history,” and wrote “the only possible novel about the past ... the struggle of the serf or citizen against the nobility, of the nobility against the church, of the nobility and church against the Monarchy.”9 The transmogrification of a conservative Scottish baronet into a Marxist saint is a feat only the Jesuitical Lukács could perform with such dexterity. Nevertheless, his jargonistic reference to “the progressive tendency” does indeed draw attention to the way in which Scott’s career demonstrated that conservatism was by no means incompatible with a belief in social, political and scientific  progress. Contemporary Britain supplied numerous examples of this phenomenon: it was the young Tory, Benjamin Disraeli, who pointed out in his novel Sybil (1846)  that Britain consisted of two nations, the rich and the poor, and aspired in his political career to make of these two nations one in which all had a stake.10 Sir Robert Peel’s abolition of  the corn laws may surely be seen as a progressive measure, especially when one looks at the sort of politicians who have from time to time subsequently urged a return to protectionism. Scott himself was a political conservative, Hanoverian loyalist and the founder of a journal (The Quarterly Review) that often expressed highly reactionary opinions, though these were not in articles written by Scott himself.
What is superficially a paradox about Scott has a simple internal logic: in his fiction and antiquarianism he rehabilitated pre-Reformation Scotland, the history which had been largely suppressed and always denigrated by the kirk. It was a revival of the past that rejoined the separated strands of Scottishness, the creation of a healing mythology that addressed itself also to a more pluralistic, hopefully more tolerant present. This was not only a Scottish, but indubitably a British tendency, a form of Vergangenheitsbewältigung whereby reform and progress, to be assured of success, had to be presented in conservative guise, the workings of what Disraeli drily characterized as “sound Conservative government ... Tory men and Whig measures.” This characteristic of the British certainly did not go unnoticed by Hungarian visitors such as Ferenc Pulszky, who comments in his journal of his English journey: “One comes to a people which, in view of the political reform is placed before all other peoples, but where one finds everywhere the most conservative custom and habits that are sanctified by centuries of use, das System des Stillstandes, which, driven out of politics, has taken root in fashion.”11  The survival, up to the second millennium, of an Upper House largely based on inheritance suggests that Pulszky was being over-generous in asserting that conservatism had been “driven out of politics”, but he had spotted one of the ways in which the British ruling elite managed change without losing face.

Notes

1 Jerry Z. Muller, Adam Smith in His Time and Ours. Princeton, 1993. pp. 22–23.
2 Robert Walsh, Narrative of a Journey from Constantinople to England. London, 1832. p. 302.
3 John Paget, Hungary and Transylvania (2 Vols.). London, 1839. Vol. 1. pp. 120–121.
4 For a detailed examination of the synthesis achieved between Romanticism and the empiricism of the Enlightenment, see Mihály Szegedy-Maszák, “Enlightenment and Liberalism in the Works of Széchenyi, Kemény and Eötvös” (from which this remark is taken) in: Hungary and European Civilisation, ed. György Ránki. Budapest. p. 24.
5 I have taken the details of this meeting and Kossuth’s remarks from Neville C. Masterman: “Gladstone’s Meeting with Kossuth”. New Hungarian Quarterly Vol. XXII No. 82. Summer 1981. pp. 179–180.
6 See László Péter, “Language, the Constitution and the Past in Hungarian Nationalism” in: The Habsburg Legacy: National Identity in Historical Perspective. Austrian Studies 5. Ed. Ritchie Robertson and Edward Timms. Edinburgh, 1994. p.17.
7 Muller, op. cit. p. 184.
8 Walter Bagehot, “Adam Smith as a Person” (1876), reprinted in The Works of Walter Bagehot.Vol. 3. Hartford, 1889. p. 277.
9 Georg Lukács, The Historical Novel. Originally published in Russian, 1937; this English translation from the German by Hannah and Stanley Mitchell. London, 1982. pp. 63, 83.
10 Sybil by Benjamin Disraeli (first published 1845). London – New York, 1985. Book IV. Ch. 8. p. 299. “I was told that the Privileged and the People formed Two Nations”.
11 Ferenc Pulszky, Aus dem Tagebuche eines in Großbritannien reisenden Ungarn. Pesth, 1837, p. 5.


Our e-mail: books @c3.hu

http://www.c3.hu/scripta


C3 Alapítvány       c3.hu/scripta/